Phillips v. Smith, 4 N.C. 475, 1 Car. L. Rep. 475 (1814)

April 1814 · Supreme Court of North Carolina
4 N.C. 475, 1 Car. L. Rep. 475

Phillips v. Smith, Executor of Dry. Hoodenpyle v. M'Dowell's Executors.

In these cases special verdicts were found; the material facts of the first of which were: That the plaintiff was evicted by lawful title from a tract of land, conveyed to him in 1781, by the defendant’s testator, with a general covenant of warranty: that the purchase money of the land was £60, but that at the time of eviction in 1814, its value was £345, from the ordinary and regular rise of property.

In the other case, the verdict stated the land to be worth at the time of purchase in 1796, £200, and at the time; of finding, £750, including improvements.

Taylor, C. J.

delivered the opinion of the Court.

The questions we are called upon to decide in these cases is, whether upon an eviction, the seller of land is responsible, under his warranty, to damages to the amount of the increased value from the time of sale, and consequently for the improvements made on the premises; or whether he is bound to pay the purchaser only the value of the property at the time of sale? The British authorities do not furnish any direct decision upon this subject in relation to the action of covenant; and that it is not easy to deduce from any analogy they afford, the correct rule of adjudication, is proved by the diversity of opinion, prevalent in the American tribunals, where the question has occurred. It has been investigated by learned and laborious counsel, and illustrated by the researches of Judges of the highest order of intellectual excellence; yet in Massachusetts, Connecticut and South-Carolina, the rule is to allow the value at the time of eviction; in New York, Pennsylvania and Virginia, the value of the land at the time of purchase, forms the measure of damages.

*476Equal difficulty, it is probable, was experienced on this subject in first laying down the principles of the civil law, a system generally characterized by its intrinsic excellence, and by being founded in many respects on the just grounds of rational jurisprudence. An arbitrary rule was resorted to, which limited the damages to double the value of the thing sold; but the avowed principle which gave rise to the rule, was not to bind the parties beyond what they might reasonably expect the damage to amount to, from the non-performance of the contract. The principle itself is certainly conformable to natural equity, although the rule built upon it, seems better calculated to put an end to strife and uncertainty, than to reach the merits of particular cases.

Indeed we cannot hope that the practical application of any rule will obviate all inconvenience and injustice; whether the damages by referred to the time of sale, or to the time of eviction. But mature consideration has convinced us, that to allow the purchaser the original value of the land, has the strongest sanction from legal analogy, is most consonant to the mild and temperate spirit of the common law, and less likely to produce public inconvenience or individual mischief, than any other rule we could adopt.

The latter consideration, it is true, ought never to influence a decision in cases where the law speaks a clear and explicit language; but no one will deny that it merits the, highest attention, where neither scale of legal reasoning preponderates.

The only remedy by the ancient law, for a person claiming under a warranty, was the writ of warranted chartæ, in which, land itself was recovered, equal in value to the land sold at the time of sale.

There is no variance in the books upon this point. In a warranty to the feoffee made by the feoffor, if upon voucher, special matter be shewn by the vouchee, that when he en*477tered into the warranty, the land at the time of the feoffment was worth only £100, and now at the time of the voucher, it is worth £200, by the industry of the feoffee, the plaintiff in a warranted chartæ shall recover only the value as it was at the the time of sale. Jenk. Cent. 35.

If feoffor improve by buildings, yet dower shall be as it was at the seisin of the husband; for the heir is not bound to warrant, except according to the value as it was at the time of the feoffment, and so the wife would recover more against the feoffor, than he would recover in value. Co. Litt. note 193.

The leading cases on this subject are copiously and elaborately stated by Mr. Luther Martin, in an opinion given by him, to be found in that useful work, Mr. Hall's Law Journal.

The warrantia chartæ, which was a mixed action, calling for judgment on the warranty as well as for damages, has given place to the action of covenant, which pledges the personal as well as the real assets, to the performance of the covenants. In this respect the remedy is more effectual and obligatory than the ancient one; but there does not seem to be any adequate reason for adopting a different rule of compensation.

The real intention and honest understanding of the parties, ought always to be considered in expounding and enforcing their contracts. Nothing could be more unreasonable, than to interpose a mode of computing damages, which in all probability, was not contemplated by either of the parties at the time of contract, and which, if then brought into view, Would have prevented its completion.

It is certainly repugnant to our ordinary conceptions of justice, that a person who sold land of little worth a few years ago, which now, by cutting a canal, or other expensive *478improvements, hath increased in value beyond all reasonable anticipation, should be liable to the purchaser to the full amount at the time of eviction. It would be doing violence to the spirit and general course of such transactions, to imagine, that the seller, at least, calculated upon such a result. He has no control over the conduct of the purchaser, who may conduct his improvements in any manner, and push them to any extent, which views of profit, pecuniary ability, taste, o r caprice may suggest.

A wealthy man may purchase from one in moderate circumstances, a spot of ground on which he expends large sums of money, either with the view of commercial profit, or in the gratification of a luxurious and costly rage for improvement; and thus, when the defect in title is discovered, the property is of greater value than the seller is able to pay. That the property should increase in value, and that the purchaser should improve it, were circumstances, which might have been reasonably expected by the seller; but it is difficult to believe, that he should, for an insignificant consideration have calmly calculated upon the total ruin of himself and family, in the possible event of a future eviction of the purchaser.

The truth is, that in fair sales, and to such alone can the rule now established apply, both parties have a confidence in the goodness of the title. The seller possesses no knowledge cencerning it, which is not equally accessible to the buyer, who receives a warranty, that in the event of the title proving defective, he may be restored to the situation he would have been in, had he never purchased. If, according to the common apprehension of mankind, the purposes of a warranty were more extensive than this; if its design were to indemnify the purchaser for the loss of his bargain, and the value of his improvements, would it not be customary to require something more than the security of the deed, when it was intended to incur great expense in improvement?

*479Let the title continue unimpeached, the increasing value of the property is the gain of the buyer; the seller can claim no addition to the price. But if the title prove defective, the buyer will still recover the value of the land, as it was when he purchased, although it may be diminished at the time of the eviction. In both cases, the same rule of compensation should be applied.

Many cases have been stated, and may again be adverted to, which demonstrate the extravagant hardship of a contrary rule.

Land is sold for a small price, on which, before eviction, a gold mine may be discovered, as in Cabarrus County; a flourishing town may be erected on it, as is the case in many parts of the State;-or it may become unexpectedly valuable for agricultural purposes, by being connected with a navigable stream, of which an instance occurs in that immense body of land, lying on Lake Phelps, and which, before the Canal was cut connecting it with Albemarle Sound, was held in comparatively small estimation. Indeed, without any extraordinary means of improvement, the increase in the value of lands, in many parts of the State, has been so great and rapid, as to baffle calculation, and deceive foresight.

Those who are conversant with Courts of Justice, know, that the early patents produced on trials in some parts of the State, have studiously left out lands then deemed of no value, (not worth the taxes) which now, by draining, or in some instances, by the increased evaporations from clearing the grounds, have become the most productive.

Any other rule of computing damages, than that of the value at the time of sale, would, in our opinion, produce the most glaring injustice, and the wide spread ruin and impoverishment of families. Nor is the principle varied because the jury, in one of these cases, have found that the increased value of the land, arose from the ordinary and regular rise *480of property. Some rule must be established as a guide to the community; for it would produce endless inconvenience to constitute the jury chancellors in each particular case, and it is impossible to take any intermediate period between the sale and eviction.

We have adopted that which refers to the sale, from a belief that if the authorities do not amount to precise demonstration on the point, they at least raise a strong probability that the law is so; and because such rule appears to us equitable, rational, and most consonant to the views and understanding of the contracting parties.